Coalition
building and our presidential system
Patrya Pratama ; The writer, studying at the London
School of Economics and Political Science in the UK, co-authored a chapter on
Indonesia’s legislature in a book by Zheng Yongnian titled Parliaments in
Asia: Institution Building and Political
Development
|
JAKARTA
POST, 17 April 2014
As soon
as the legislative election quick count results were released, the discourse
on coalition building among political parties began.
It is
not only that coalitions need to be formed to contest the upcoming
presidential election in July, as no party (at least according to quick
counts) reached 20 percent of legislative seats or 25 percent of the popular
vote, but coalitions are also necessary to ensure strong support in the House
of Representatives for who wins the presidency.
It is
interesting to see two different approaches to coalition building from the
two most likely contenders, Jakarta Governor Joko “Jokowi” Widodo of the
Indonesian Democratic Party of Struggle (PDI-P) and Prabowo Subianto of the
Gerindra Party.
While
Jokowi emphasized that Cabinet portfolio negotiations for potential coalition
members were off the table, in an effort to strengthen presidentialism,
Prabowo has offered a “power sharing” (or “big tent” coalition according to
Gerindra’s Fadli Zon) mechanism for its coalition. In short, this means
offering Cabinet seats to coalition members.
How will
these approaches impact on our system of government in the next five years?
The term
“coalition” is alien in any presidential system. It is more common to find it
in a parliamentary system, such as in the UK.
Usually,
a coalition is formed if no political parties reach 50 percent+1 of seats in
the parliament to ensure a stable government.
It has
been an increasing phenomenon in Western Europe for the last five decades
where coalitions have been needed due to decreasing support for the main
political parties, making smaller size parties the “king-makers”.
In the
last UK general election, the decision of the Liberal Democrat Party to form
a coalition with the Conservative Party made UK Prime Minister David
Cameron’s government possible.
Although
a minority government (wherein the ruling government’s parliamentary support
is less than 50 percent+1) is theoretically possible, largely, a coalition to
ensure 50 percent+1 of parliamentary seats is pursued.
Does all
this apply to Indonesia’s presidential system? It depends.
Theoretically,
in presidential systems coalitions are not needed. Since the president is
elected directly by the people, unlike prime ministers in parliamentary
systems, presidents are guaranteed five-year terms no matter what.
According
to this line of reasoning, there is no need for an Indonesian president to
“share” Cabinet seats with coalition members.
This
line of reasoning is apparently exactly what Jokowi has taken. If his
coalition discussions with Nasdem Party chairman Surya Paloh are taken as a
reference, they did not discuss the Cabinet portfolio at all.
According
to this camp, coalition building is a “policy-seeking” exercise where parties
who agree with certain policies will naturally join the bloc.
But this
is not the complete picture.
In our
system, the president is not the only one running the show. Many laws and
policies need to be made with the House’s approval.
Hence,
to ensure that the president’s policies are supported by the House,
presidents need to form a coalition of political parties that consists of 50
percent+1 of seats in the House.
The way
of ensuring political parties to “join” the coalition is by giving them seats
in the Cabinet.
According
to political theorists Michael Lever and Kenneth A. Shepsle, the route of
Cabinet portfolio negotiation is taken as it is the most credible and
concrete negotiation subject, compared to negotiations over certain policies,
as coalition building is perceived as an “office-seeking” exercise.
This
line of reasoning is taken by Prabowo’s camp, and was also implemented during
the two terms of President Susilo Bambang Yudhoyono.
For this
camp, the “power sharing” of a Cabinet portfolio for coalition members is
simply the consequence of the political reality to ensure support in the
House, plus ensuring support during the presidential election.
So, what
is the verdict?
Each
approach has its own merit. Jokowi’s approach relies on the assumption that
as long as the executive branch’s policy initiatives are aligned with the
public interest at large, the House will always be difficult to oppose.
However,
as the Yudhoyono debacle has shown, even a much-needed policy to cut the fuel
subsidy did not pass as it did not get enough House support.
Moreover,
the presidential election is all about figureheads, making the number of
political parties supporting the candidate irrelevant.
Prabowo’s
power-sharing approach relies on the assumption that House support is
guaranteed as coalition members are expected to return the favor of being
given Cabinet seats.
However,
as Yudhoyono’s large coalition has taught us, not all of his coalition
members supported him in the House.
We
remember well how the Golkar Party and Prosperous Justice Party (PKS)
“ditched” the coalition by openly campaigning against the government on the
issues of the Bank Century bailout case and the fuel subsidy cut.
As long
as our political parties are not clearly differentiated on policies, we will
remain in the dark on why parties reject/support certain policies by the
executive branch, or why parties join one coalition bloc instead of the
other.
We must
put up with the fact that the realpolitik need to “share power” or “Cabinet
portfolio allocation” will always emerge, that is unless we give a chance for
real presidentialism to take shape by watching the policy-making process
closely to avoid politically a motivated House that simply opposes the
president for backdoor concessions. ●
|
Tidak ada komentar:
Posting Komentar