New minimum wage formula :
A labor economics perspective (Part 1 of 2)
Chris Manning ; An adjunct fellow with the Indonesia
Project
at the Australian National
University
|
JAKARTA
POST, 16 November 2015
The government finally
bit the bullet on wage reform, after three years of turbulent disputation
over minimum wages in Indonesia’s major industrial areas. This came in
mid-October as part of the raft of reforms stretching back to mid-September.
Employers have bought
greater certainty, in return for handing over all the returns from growth to
labor. Rather surprisingly, spokespersons for business said their members
were happy with the deal, according to statements from Indonesian Chamber Of
Commerce And Industry and Indonesian Employers Association representatives.
The government
believes it has clinched a deal that will contribute to a more attractive
investment climate. Revision to the minimum wage-setting process and
principles is an important reform for economic competitiveness, employment
and equity. It’s worth looking at closely, even if the deal is by no means
clinched, given an imminent challenge from some governors and the unions.
The new arrangement
has been praised for its simplicity and for taking politics out of the wage
determination process — which the governors of Jakarta and Central Java are
clearly unhappy with. The minimum wage (MW) in each region (province and
city/regency) will now be adjusted based on the national rate of growth (in real
terms) and the national increase in the cost of living, the CPI.
This formula is to be
applied to the existing MW in each region, except for a special arrangement
for catch-up in several provinces outside the main industrial areas. In 2016,
the increase is to be 11.5 percent, not too different from the previous year
in and around the national capital (it is less than in many regions outside
greater Jakarta that were trying last year to catch up to the pace setters in
regions near the capital). But by most standards it is generous for an
economy struggling in the midst of a stumbling world economy.
Taking the annual tug
of war over the changes in the decent standard of living for workers at
district level and setting of minimum wages by provincial governments must be
considered a major step forward towards a more rules-based system.
Gone will be the
pressures from ambitious union leaders and local politicians to push for
large increases in wages by international standards. Potentially, it means an
end to industrial action and political maneuvering, which meant that MWs
spiraled upwards in the main industrial regions in and around Jakarta and
Surabaya from 2010-2015 — by around 20 percent per annum in nominal terms,
and 15 percent per annum after adjusting for inflation.
From an investment
climate point of view it all seems too good to be true. But what about the
public interest? To assess this we need to go back to basics: how is the MW
related to actual wages, employment and the welfare of wage workers in
general?
Going back to first
principles, the MW were historically designed to play the role of a social
safety-net for blue collar (mostly unskilled) workers in establishments where
wages are very low.
It was argued that
many workers were exploited by employers, owing partly to “monosonistic”
conditions in the labor market, which enable some employers to push wages to
very low, inhumane levels.
A lack of bargaining
power gives often immobile, uneducated and ignorant workers little choice but
to accept these wage offers.
In reality, MW have
often been adopted by governments to play quite a different role in countries
at an early and transitional stage of development, when wages are still very
low.
The authorities have
in reality sought to regulate the “entry level” of wages into jobs for most
blue collar workers, partly to garner political support and partly with the
aim of improving the general standard of living of wage workers. Thus the MW
does not just apply to those in firms paying wages at the bottom-end of the
wage distribution.
However,
implementation of such a policy is complicated by a dualistic (some say
differentiated) structure of wages, which is especially evident in developing
countries. At the heart of it is a large gap in productivity and wages
between the modern and traditional sectors.
This complicates
policy enormously, combined with low levels of unionization and a limited
administrative capacity to implement policy in smaller firms. Often MW only
apply to the modern sector, and even here coverage may be far from complete;
on the other hand, wage workers in smaller firms are rarely covered by the
MW, even though these establishments account for around half and often more
of all wage employees.
The above description
mirrors the case in Indonesia. The recent, rapid increases in the MW have
strengthened this tendency. Thus wages are not determined by productivity for
the modern sector workers but by the whims of the government and the
bargaining process among unions and employers.
Trends in unit labor
costs — the cost of wages to the employer, relative to productivity — in this
part of the economy, which accounts for around one third of all jobs are
estimated to have risen sharply in recent years. Importantly, the modern sector
includes many of the large, labor-intensive and often export-oriented firms
that have provided better jobs for many rural-urban migrants in past periods
of rapid growth.
These firms have been
struggling in recent years, partly because of high wage costs relative to
productivity. If minimum wages are to play the role of a social safety net,
and wage revisions to reflect changes in productivity, thus contributing to
economic progress, one challenge for Indonesia is to reconnect wages and
productivity, especially in internationally competitive industries. Let’s
assume that doing away with minimum wages altogether — as some economists
would recommend — is not an option politically.
Then the strategy for
safeguarding jobs is to “decouple” MW setting from actual wages paid by most
enterprises. That is, over time, MW are increasingly based on wages paid to
most workers in the traditional sector, and really act as a social safety net
for wages paid by greedy managers below this standard. ●
|
Tidak ada komentar:
Posting Komentar