Next
generation of microfinance :
Leveraging
Indonesian experience
Muhammad Shodiq ;
The head
of the Sahabat Financial Institute and the group head of human capital
development at the Sampoerna Financial Group, Jakarta
|
JAKARTA
POST, 11 September 2014
The
history of microfinance institutions in Indonesia dates back more than 100
years. The primary reason for their initial establishment was to combat
extortionate lending practices in rural areas and to impose tight
restrictions on money lenders. The first rural bank in Indonesia was the
Hulp-en Spaar Bank der Indlandsche Bestuurs Ambtenaren or Bank for Civil
Servants, founded by R. Bei Aria Wiraadmadja in 1895. The bank then expanded
its operations to farmers and other local residents and offered saving facilities
at fair interest rates.
Many
“paddy banks” or Lumbung Desa institutions were also established to provide
savings and loans facilities for rice farmers. During the colonial period,
the Lumbung Desa, Bank Desa, farmer banks, market banks and village trade
credit institutions became the pioneers of microfinance in Indonesia and the
forerunners of today’s rural banks. In the 1970s, microfinance institutions
became established throughout the country under government sponsorship for
Village Fund and Credit Institutions (LDKP).
In
1992, the government enacted a new Banking Law that extended formal
recognition to rural banks as distinct from commercial banks. This law also
allowed a transition period for LDKP to transform themselves into rural banks
by fulfilling the specific requirements applicable to rural banks.
The
relationship between lenders and borrowers is characterized by the asymmetry
of information. There are two main problems: Adverse selection and moral
risk. The first involves the creditor’s lack of knowledge in relation to the
type of borrower; that is, the lender does not know how risk-inclined the
borrower is, or how honest, how responsible, etc. On the other hand, moral
risk involves the lender’s lack of information regarding the type of action
the borrower can have. In this particular case, it is in relation to what the
borrower will do with the loan and what type of investment he or she will
choose.
Stiglitz
and Weiss (1979) describe how the rationing of credit occurs in equilibrium.
According to them, the bank’s return does not always grow with the interest
rate increase, since after a certain point of increase in the rates, there is
a reduction in the average quality of borrowers.
This
leads to the attraction of less honest and less well-intentioned borrowers,
or simply those with more risk and who are more inclined to perform riskier
investments, therefore reducing the compliance rate, due to a simultaneous
problem of adverse selection and moral risk.
There
is an optimal interest rate, which therefore brings maximum return to the
banks, and if there are more credit buyers than suppliers for the interest
rate, there will be credit rationing. That is, many agents will not have
access to credit even though they are willing to pay a higher interest rate.
Microfinance
providers in Indonesia are currently divided into formal and informal
sectors. In the formal sectors, at least 15 out of 120 commercial banks run
special divisions of microfinance, and in addition there are, 1,667 rural
banks, 155 Islamic rural banks, 600,000 microfinance institutions and
cooperatives, 5,500 Islamic microfinance institutions and more than 500 zakat
(alms) fund institutions.
The
players in the vast informal microfinance sector range from various NGOs, community
self-help groups (PHBK), money lenders, informal savings and loans groups and
informal cooperatives. The number of informal entities in operation possibly
exceeds 40 million, spurred by economic growth in rural areas that has led to
a significant increase in small and medium enterprises (SMEs).
Indonesian
commercial banks have become a success story in terms of micro-lending by
commercial banks.
The
most important players among microfinance institutions in Indonesia are the
commercial banks and the rural banks. These are regarded as representing the
best Indonesian experience in the development of microfinance institutions.
Below
are major players in microfinance in Indonesia:
Commercial
banks’ achievements demonstrate that financial services to
micro-entrepreneurs can generate a commercially competitive rate of return
and achieve the strategic goals of commercial banks.
The
key success factors of Indonesian commercial banks in microfinance are: loans
based on the needs and repayment capacity of the borrowers; retention of good
borrowers and use of debtor performance as a key consideration in subsequent
borrowings; provision of simple and professional services to customers; close
supervision of loan performance by assigning special supervisors; simple
administrative procedures; and efficient organizational structure with limits
on staff numbers to keep overhead costs low.
While
rural banks are part of the banking system, they operate under specific
limitations. Rural banks are only permitted to accept savings and provide
loans.
Despite
these limitations, rural banks have the advantage of their location in rural
and urban areas, which affords close proximity to their specific market
segments.
They
are able to identify potential clients and maintain relationships with
depositors as well as debtor customers. ●
|
Tidak ada komentar:
Posting Komentar